hal.structure.identifier | | |
dc.contributor.author | Keppler, Jan-Horst | * |
dc.date.accessioned | 2012-09-18T07:23:16Z | |
dc.date.available | 2012-09-18T07:23:16Z | |
dc.date.issued | 2012 | |
dc.identifier.uri | https://basepub.dauphine.fr/handle/123456789/10019 | |
dc.language.iso | en | en |
dc.subject | Electricity | en |
dc.subject | Costs | en |
dc.subject | Nuclear Phase-Out | en |
dc.subject.ddc | 333 | en |
dc.subject.classificationjel | Q.Q5.Q53 | en |
dc.subject.classificationjel | Q.Q4.Q43 | en |
dc.title | The economic costs of the nuclear phase-out in Germany | en |
dc.type | Article accepté pour publication ou publié | |
dc.description.abstracten | In the immediate aftermath of the March 2011
TEPCO Fukushima Daiichi nuclear power plant
accident, the German federal government decided
to temporarily halt the operation of the country’s
eight oldest energy-producing nuclear reactors. This
was accompanied by a cabinet proposal to phase out
all 17 of the country’s nuclear reactors, which have
a combined capacity of 20.5 GW, by 2022. On 31 July
2011 the proposal became law, and the temporary
shutdown of the eight reactors was converted into
a permanent shutdown by 6 August 2011. Shutting down reactors with an average lifetime of 33.5 years (compared to an industry standard of at least 40 years and in some countries, such as the United States, of 60 years) imposes significant costs on German power producers, electricity consumers and the German economy. This article estimates the direct costs linked to the shutdown of Germany’s nuclear power reactors before the end of their operational lifetimes. These are costs that are
immediately passed on in the form of higher costs
for electricity producers or higher prices for electricity
consumers. The direct costs of the shutdown take on three
forms: a) the costs for constructing and operating
replacement capacity on the supply side, b) higher
electricity prices and a concomitant loss of consumer
surplus on the demand side, and c) increased electricity
imports. The costs for replacement capacity
can be subdivided into additional investments costs,
higher operating costs and higher costs for transport
and distribution to the extent that replacement
capacity is composed of decentralised renewables
located far from final consumers. Higher electricity
prices are due in the short term to a reduction of
capacity margins (which means that equipment with
higher operating costs will need to be employed),
and in the long run due to an increase in the prices
of gas, coal and carbon due to additional demand.
A crucial element in determining the cost of the
decision of the German government to phase out
nuclear power is the baseline against which the
costs of the electricity system resulting from the
phase-out decision need to be assessed. This exercise
takes the situation immediately preceding the
phase-out decision in March 2011 as its baseline. | en |
dc.relation.isversionofjnlname | NEA News | |
dc.relation.isversionofjnlvol | 30 | en |
dc.relation.isversionofjnlissue | 1 | en |
dc.relation.isversionofjnldate | 2012 | |
dc.relation.isversionofjnlpages | 8-14 | en |
dc.identifier.urlsite | http://www.oecd-nea.org/nea-news/2012/30-1/nea-news-30-1.pdf | en |
dc.relation.isversionofjnlpublisher | OECD | en |
dc.subject.ddclabel | Economie de la terre et des ressources naturelles | en |
dc.relation.forthcoming | non | en |
dc.relation.forthcomingprint | non | en |
dc.description.halcandidate | oui | |
dc.description.readership | recherche | |
dc.description.audience | International | |
dc.relation.Isversionofjnlpeerreviewed | non | |
hal.identifier | hal-01609472 | * |
hal.version | 1 | * |
hal.update.action | updateMetadata | * |
hal.author.function | aut | |